communist Hungary asserted precisely that. The Intellectuals on the Road to Class Power, by novelist Gyorgy Konrad and sociologist Ivan Szelenyi, argued that Marx’s vision of a communist state run by the working class, or indeed of an eventual utopia in which the state withered away entirely, had been perverted. Instead, a new class had seized power: the class of engineers, economists, physicists, and, yes, even poets—which is to say, the intellectuals.

Konrad and Szelenyi’s book was a revolutionary act—its authors retreated to a village in the Buda Hills to write it in an effort to evade the secret police, and they buried their manuscript in the garden every night, to protect it from being seized in a feared early morning raid. The book caused a predictable splash when it was published in the West in 1979, five years after it had been written—this was, after all, the beginning of the final triumphant chapter of the cold war, the year Ronald Reagan was elected and Leonid Brezhnev was starting the fifteenth year of his reign as general secretary of the Communist Party of the Soviet Union. Anything that discredited the so-called workers’ paradise, particularly from the inside, was a geopolitical event.

The Intellectuals on the Road to Class Power built on the arguments of an even more groundbreaking work smuggled out of Eastern Europe a generation earlier: Milovan Djilas’s The New Class. Writing in the seventies, Konrad and Szelenyi were themselves members of the somewhat threadbare but socially cosseted socialist intelligentsia they described, though they were not members of the Communist Party. Djilas—Tito’s right-hand man during the partisan struggle and his emissary to Stalin’s Kremlin court—belonged to the earlier revolutionary generation. Djilas’s book, which earned its writer a seven-year prison sentence in the same jail he had been sent to for his revolutionary activities in the 1930s, was an instant international sensation, and rightly so. It was the first time a senior Soviet bloc official publicly condemned the system he had helped to create. Written thirteen years after George Orwell had made the same charge in his allegorical Animal Farm, Djilas made the ideologically devastating argument that the so- called workers’ state had simply replaced the old ruling bourgeoisie with a new class, the communist apparat. He even estimated the material gap between this new elite and the people it ruled, citing Soviet dissident Yuri Orlov’s report that a rayon secretary—the head of a provincial or city party organization—earned about twenty-five times more than the average worker.

The important twist Konrad and Szelenyi added to this analysis was that the rule of this new class actually amounted to a seizure of political and economic power by the intellectuals—heredity and military might determined power under feudalism; money and commercial acumen were the source of control under capitalism. Under communism, they asserted, technical skills and higher education were the most important defining characteristics of the new party elite.

There was a lot of truth to their analysis, and it is one reason some members of the old Eastern European and Soviet intelligentsias, not to mention their friends in the West, are nostalgic for the old order. But if you read The Intellectuals on the Road to Class Power today, the most striking paradox about this dissident dissection of Warsaw Pact socialism is how powerfully it applies to twenty-first-century global capitalism. For the intellectual class Konrad and Szelenyi studied, highly educated technocrats, the collapse of communism, and the emergence of a global market economy turned out to be the true road to class power.

The language of twenty-first-century Western economists is rather less colorful than that of 1970s central European dissidents. That’s why you won’t find many references to the rise of the technocrats to class power in the American academic debate of the early twenty-first century. But there is intense study of the impact of “skill-biased technical change” on income distribution, particularly in the developed Western economies. The consensus, advanced most powerfully by MIT economist David Autor, is that skill-biased technical change has indeed brought the technocrats to class power. As Autor puts it, it has polarized the labor market, with huge rewards for those at the top, who have the skills and education to take advantage of new technologies, not much impact for those who do the low-paying “lousy” jobs at the bottom, and a hollowing out of the well-paying jobs in between that used to support the middle class.

There is, of course, a fierce debate about what is causing rising income inequality, and the most honest students of the phenomenon attribute it to a number of factors. But there is broad agreement that skill-biased technical change is a crucial, and possibly the crucial, factor. In a January 2012 speech about income inequality, Alan Krueger, a Princeton economist who now heads President Barack Obama’s Council of Economic Advisers, reported one indicator of that consensus. In the mid-1990s he polled a nonrandom group of professional economists attending a conference at the New York Fed. They overwhelmingly named technological change as the main driver of income polarization—more than 40 percent said it was the chief cause. In a touching sign of humility, the second most popular explanation was “unknown.” Third was globalization. Political shifts, like the decline in the minimum wage and the decline in unionization, came in behind these top three.

There’s another reason the rise of the intellectuals to class power in global capitalism isn’t always immediately apparent within that favored group. That’s because not all of the highly educated are prospering equally. If you have a PhD in English literature, you probably don’t feel you are a member of the ruling elite. And even within tribes whose training vaults them collectively into the 1 percent—like bankers, lawyers, or computer programmers—there’s a twist to the impact of skills-biased technological change that lessens the sense of group prosperity. This is what economists call the “superstar” effect—the tendency of both technological change and globalization to create winner-take-all economic tournaments in many sectors and companies, where being the most successful in your field delivers huge rewards, but coming in second place, and certainly in fifth or tenth, has much less economic value.

The triumph of the nerds is intuitively obvious in the postindustrial economies of the developed West, where brains have had more value than brawn for a couple of generations. But in today’s era of the twin gilded ages, the triumph of the intellectuals is a global phenomenon. The highly educated are in the vanguard of India’s outsourcing miracle; the intellectuals, especially their “technical” branch, are very much in charge in communist China; and even the Russian oligarchs, who are better known in the West for their yachts and supermodel consorts, overwhelmingly have advanced degrees in math and physics.

The rise of the geeks, particularly the super-achievers among them, is a sharp break from the postwar era, when the robust economic recovery in the United States and western Europe was driven by the rise of a vast, and culturally dominant, middle class, much of it employed in blue-collar or relatively routine midlevel clerical, administrative, and managerial jobs. The disappearance of these opportunities, at a time when the super-smart are prospering as never before, is one reason for the populist antipathy toward the nerds. The impulse is strikingly bipartisan—the conservative Tea Party is every bit as hostile toward elites as is Occupy Wall Street, which has defined itself as the forum of the 99 percent.

Ironically—and frustratingly, for those in the discontented middle—the class power of the intellectuals is such that they are rising to the top of the political heap on both the left and the right. Indeed, at a time of fierce partisan conflict, one of the striking paradoxes is how much the champions of liberals and conservatives have in common: Mitt Romney and Barack Obama are both disciplined, dogged millionaires who describe their more popular wives as their better halves, hold degrees from Harvard Law School, and have a preference for data-driven arguments rather than emotional ones. Both men struggle to connect with the grassroots of their parties, coming across as cold and robotic.

You might call it the cognitive divide—the split between an evidence-based worldview and one rooted in faith or ideology—and it is one of the most important fault lines in America today. To his critics on the right, Obama is a socialist with dangerous foreign antecedents. To his critics on the left, he is a waffler with no real point of view and a craven desire to be liked. But the best explanation is that, like the rest of the rising intellectual class to which he belongs, the president is an empiricist. He wants to do what works, not what conforms to any particular ideology or what pleases any particular constituency. His core belief is a belief in facts.

Obama the empiricist is not the man who surged from behind to win the 2008 presidential election. That candidate was the Obama of soaring rhetoric, who promised hope and change. But the pragmatist has always been there. Writing in September 2008, several weeks before the presidential elections, Cass Sunstein, who has gone on to serve in the White House, had this to say about his candidate: “Above all, Obama’s form of pragmatism is heavily empirical; he wants to know what will work.” Word crunchers found that the president’s 2009 inaugural address was the first one to use the term “data” and only the second to mention “statistics.”

That cognitive approach is one reason Obama attracted so much support, especially among the younger generation, on Wall Street and in Silicon Valley. That wasn’t some sentimental betrayal of class interests—what Lenin is said to have called the useful idiocy of the capitalists who bankrolled the Bolsheviks; it was a recognition

Вы читаете Plutocrats
Добавить отзыв
ВСЕ ОТЗЫВЫ О КНИГЕ В ИЗБРАННОЕ

0

Вы можете отметить интересные вам фрагменты текста, которые будут доступны по уникальной ссылке в адресной строке браузера.

Отметить Добавить цитату