for chemical substances (as opposed to chemical processes). The reasoning was that those substances, unlike mechanical inventions, already existed in nature and, therefore, the ‘inventor’ had merely found a way to isolate them, rather than inventing the substance itself. Chemical substances remained unpatentable in Switzerland until 1978.
Switzerland was not the only country at the time without a patent law. The Netherlands actually abolished its 1817 patent law in 1869, not to introduce it again until 1912. When the Dutch abolished the law, they were in no small measure influenced by the anti-patent movement I mentioned above – they were convinced that patent, as artificially created monopoly, went against their free-trade principle.[25] Exploiting the absence of a patent law, the Dutch electronics company, Philips, a household name today, started out in 1891 as a producer of light bulbs based on the patents ‘borrowed’ from the American inventor, Thomas Edison.[26]
Switzerland and the Netherlands may have been extreme cases. But throughout much of the 19th century, the IPR regimes in today’s rich countries were all very bad at protecting
‘Borrowing’ ideas was not simply done in relation to inventions that could be patented. There was also extensive counterfeiting of trademarks in the 19th century – in a manner similar to what was subsequently done by Japan, Korea, Taiwan and, today, China. In 1862, Britain revised its trademark law, the Merchandise Mark Act, with the specific purpose of preventing foreigners, especially the Germans, from making counterfeit English products. The revised act required the producer to specify the place or country of manufacture as a part of the necessary ‘trade description’.[29]
The law underestimated German ingenuity, however – the German firms came up with some brilliant evasive tactics.[30] For example, they placed the stamp indicating the country of origin on the packaging instead of on the individual articles. Once the packaging was removed, customers could not tell the product’s country of origin. This technique is said to have been particularly common in the case of imported watches and steel files. Alternatively, German manufacturers would send some articles, like pianos and bicycles, over in pieces and have them assembled in England. Or they would place the stamp indicating the country of origin where it was practically invisible. The 19th-century British journalist Ernest Williams, who wrote a book about German counterfeiting,
Copyrights were also routinely violated. Despite its currently gung-ho attitude towards copyright, the US in the past refused to protect foreigners’ copyrights in its 1790 copyright law. It only signed the international copyright agreement (the Berne Convention of 1886) in 1891. At the time, the US was a net importer of copyright materials and saw the advantage of protecting only American authors. For another century (until 1988), it did not recognize copyrights on materials printed outside the US.
The historical picture is clear. Counterfeiting was not invented in modern Asia.When they were backward themselves in terms of knowledge, all of today’s rich countries blithely violated other people’s patents, trademarks and copyrights. The Swiss ‘borrowed’ German chemical inventions, while the Germans ‘borrowed’ English trademarks and the Americans ‘borrowed’British copyrighted materials – all without paying what would today be considered ‘just’ compensation.
Despite this history, the Bad Samaritan rich countries are now forcing developing countries to strengthen the protection of intellectual property rights to a historically unprecedented degree through the TRIPS agreement and a raft of bilateral free-trade agreements. They argue that stronger protection of intellectual property will encourage the production of new knowledge and benefit everyone, including the developing countries. But is this true?
In 1998, the US Copyright Term Extension Act extended the period of copyright protection from ‘life of the author plus 50 years, or 75 years for a work of corporate authorship’ (as set in 1976) to ‘life of the author plus 70 years, or 95 years for a work of corporate authorship’.Historically speaking, this was an incredible extension in the period of copyright protection from the original 14 years (renewable for another 14 years) laid down by the 1790 Copyright Act.
The 1998 act is derisively known as the Mickey Mouse Protection Act, from the fact that Disney was heading the lobby for it in anticipation of the 75th birthday of Mickey Mouse, first created in 1928 (
The story does not end with copyrights. The US pharmaceutical industry has already successfully lobbied to extend
It is not just in the US that the terms of IPR protection have been lengthening. In the third quarter of the 19th century (1850–75), the average patent life in a sample of 60 countries was around 13 years. Between 1900 and 1975, this was extended to 16 or 17 years. But recently the US has played the leading role in accelerating and consolidating this upward trend. It has now made its 20-year term for patent protection a ‘global standard’ through enshrining it in the World Trade Organisation’s TRIPS agreement – the 60-country average stood at 19 years as of 2004.[33] Anything that goes beyond TRIPS, such as the
As the protection of intellectual property rights involves monopoly (and its social costs), extending the period of protection clearly increases those costs. Lengthening the term – like any other strengthening of IPR protection – means that society is paying more for new knowledge. Of course, those costs may be justified if the term extension produces more knowledge (by strengthening the incentive for innovation), but there is no evidence that this has been happening – at least not enough to compensate for the increased costs of protection. Given this, we need to carefully examine whether the current terms of IPR protection are appropriate and shorten them if necessary.
One basic assumption behind IPR laws is that the new idea that is awarded protection is worth protecting.This is why all such laws demand the idea to be original (to possess ‘novelty’ and ‘non-obviousness’, in the technical jargon). This may sound incontrovertible in abstract terms, but it is more difficult to put into practice, not least because investors have an incentive to lobby for lowering the originality bar.
For example, as I mentioned when discussing the history of Swiss patent law, many people believe that chemical