game theory.’ ”
“Well, Webmind certainly needs to understand human behavior better.”
“Okay,” said her mom. “Let’s go downstairs.”
Her mother got a clipboard, some pens, and some paper, and the two of them went to the dining room, which had a big table. There was normally one chair on each side of the table, but Caitlin’s mom moved hers to be next to Caitlin’s.
“Webmind
The word
“Okay,” her mom said. “Do you know what the prisoner’s dilemma is?”
Caitlin thought,
Her mother seemed to consider for a moment, then: “Okay, let’s do it like this: say you and Bashira both get in trouble at school. Say Principal Auerbach has said that he thinks you guys have hacked into the school’s computer and changed your grades—just like in
Caitlin nodded, and her mother went on. “But the principal’s real interest is in making sure this never happens again, so he adds that if you’ll say Bashira did it and explain how it was done, you get off scot-free—no suspension at all—and he’ll suspend Bashira for three weeks. Oh, except for this: if you say Bashira did it, and Bashira says
Caitlin didn’t hesitate. “I clam up; I don’t say a word.”
“But if Bashira fingers you, you’ll get three weeks of suspension.”
“But she
Her mother seemed to consider this. “Okay, okay, let’s say it’s not you and Bashira for the moment. Let’s say it’s just two random guys—um, Frank and Dale. What should you do if you’re Frank?”
Caitlin suppressed a smile. Frank was the name of her mother’s first husband, who had come and gone long before she’d been born, and Dale, she knew, was the former head of the Economics Department at the University of Houston—someone her mother had famously not gotten along with. Picking truly random people was as hard as generating really random numbers, it seemed.
Still, the math was easy. “I rat out Dale,” Caitlin said.
“Why?”
“Because it’s the best thing for me. If he doesn’t rat me out, I get away without any punishment, instead of having a one-week suspension. And if he
“And what about Dale? What should he do?”
Caitlin frowned. “Well, I guess he should rat me out, too.”
“Why?”
“The same reasons: no matter what I do, he gets one week less suspension by turning me in.”
Her mother smiled—but whether at Caitlin’s brilliance or at the thought of both Frank and Dale being punished, she couldn’t say. “Exactly,” her mom said, and she started to draw on the paper. “If we make a chart with Frank’s possible moves—we call them ‘defecting’ or ‘cooperating’—on the x-axis and Dale’s possible moves— the same things, defect or cooperate—on the y-axis, we get what’s called the payoff matrix: a table with a score for each possible outcome, see?” She pointed at one of the squares in the matrix. “Even though the best possible outcome—one week’s punishment—occurs when you both cooperate, the math says you should
Caitlin frowned again. If game theory was all about people being selfish, it wasn’t going to help her accomplish what she wished with Webmind; she needed a way to make it want to act altruistically.
“Now,” her mom went on, “that’s a simple game: each player only got to make one move. But most games involve a series of turns. Consider a dollar bill—”
“We’re in Canada now, Mom,” Caitlin said, teasing. “They don’t have dollar bills.” She knew the Canadian one-dollar coin was called a loonie, because it had a picture of a loon—a kind of waterfowl—on the tails side. She also knew that the two-dollar coin was called a toonie. She thought a much more clever name would have been “doubloon,” but nobody had asked her.
“Fine,” her mother said, smiling. “Consider a dollar
Caitlin nodded.
“How much, on average, do you think the dollar sells for?”
She lifted her shoulders. “Fifty cents?”
“Nope. The average is $3.40.”
“That’s crazy!” said Caitlin.
“Loony, even,” her mother replied. “But it’s true.”
“Why do people bid so high?”
“Well, remember, the second-highest bidder has to pay the auctioneer, too, so…” She trailed off, clearly wanting Caitlin to figure it out for herself.
She tried to do so. The first bidder presumably bid a penny to start—which would net him a ninety-nine-cent profit. But then as soon as a second bidder offered two cents, the first bidder probably figured that offering three cents was still a good deal: he’d net ninety-seven cents in profit.
And so it would continue, until—
Ah!
Until one bidder bid ninety-nine cents—which would still give him a one-cent profit. But the previous bidder, whose bid might have been, say, ninety-eight cents, was now looking at losing that much and getting nothing in return. And so
And so, indeed, it would escalate, with bids going higher and higher, until the utter ridiculousness of the situation finally caused all but one of the bidders to drop out.
Caitlin said as much to her mom, who smiled encouragingly. “That’s right, dear. Now, can you think of what the
Caitlin considered for a second then: “Make an opening bid of ninety-nine cents. No one else would have any motive to bid against you, because the best they could do, if they outbid you by one cent, is break even, and if they bid more, they’d lose money. You’d end up being the only bidder, and you’d still make a profit, even if it’s only a penny.”
“That’s right,” her mother said again, “assuming all the potential bidders were rational and that their only motive
“Yes?”
“Suppose it was your worst enemy who had just bid ninety-nine cents. You might bid, say, $1.98, just so he’d be out almost a buck—and you’d still be out less than he was.”
“Wow,” Caitlin said. “That’s nasty.”
“I’ve seen this game get very ugly at parties,” her mom said. “I’ve seen couples who arrived together leave