rules which seem to govern the relationship between interest rate shifts and currency movements.
1) Interest rate shifts prompted by domestic pressures (an over-heating economy, for example) tend to
2) Interest rate shifts prompted by international (and currency) pressures tend to
3) Following rule 2), a currency will tend to turn round and follow the lead of interest rates up: a) if/when they have risen around 4 points and especially, b) when the currency is perceived to have stabilised over several months (e.g. sterling in Spring 1985, and in 1990).
4) In this event, interest rates will peak when the currency troughs; and
5) When currencies are led by interest rates, their movement is directly related to the
Rule 4) is an exception to rule 1) and there are others. For example falling interest yields call for rising bond prices. The result, in the case of the major investment currencies, can be a tug-of-war, when falling interest rates might discourage international investors but rising bond prices attract them –as they did in the case of the dollar in summer 1984 to spring 1985.Finally rules) is a
Inflation and Real Yields’*
There is another exception to rule 1). If US interest rates are being pushed up because of a perception that US inflation is headed up, or if they fall because inflation is seen to be falling, you have another tug 0' war,between the short time-frame and the longer time-frame. To short-termers, higher rates may seem to support a currency: but over time, inflation corrupts a currency. So a movement in interest rates that is led by inflation is suspect: “real” interest rates may be unaffected, or even moving in the opposite direction.

This idea of real, inflation-adjusted interest rates may sometimes seem a bit academic. And indeed it’s a hybrid invention, for its two constituents occupy different time-frames. Interest rates can fluctuate violently over the short term: inflation can have big swings measured in years. But inflation is the one and only
Just as we can adjust interest for inflation to get at something closer to

the “real” picture, so we can do the same thing for currencies. It’s another academic exercise. And it’s very difficult to see how we can use “real” inflation-adjusted currency histories for any practical purpose. But it may at times be helpful for perspective. It’s difficult, for example, to look at these charts of the “real” dollar without leaping to the conclusion that the big bull market in the dollar in 1981-5 was a strange
Although “real” yields are a hybrid, the constituents are, as it were, incestuously related. For inflation expectations are a major determinant of interest rates over time; in fact they area key determinant of long term yields
In short, yield differentials and inflation differentials seem to be basic
As we know, the thing that makes prices move is

And I think this has been true ever since currencies began to float freely in 1973. Admittedly the professionals didn’t quite see it that way in the old days. But while we’re at it, we might as well blow their secret. The professionals made a bundle of money in the 1970s, and the way they made it was very simple. They only had two rules. One has been valid as far back as the memories of currency traders went: “sell the crisis. “When a currency got into trouble, all you needed to do was wait until the central bank came in to support it and then sell for all you were worth. It always worked: for sterling, the lira, French franc, whatever. The other rule, when the dollar went off the gold standard, was even simpler: “sell the dollar”.
Always, but especially if the central banks supported it. Following these two rules, the professional! cleaned up and the central banks lost a bundle.
In the 1980s, the roles were reversed and it was the central banks that cleaned up, with much loss of shirts among the professionals. Part of the trouble was that traders were introducing all sorts of complications into the currency equation to do with intrinsic values, and trade competitiveness; and they were obsessed with forecasting interest rates.
We know that expected total return has to be the ultimate value bench. mark for the currencies. If we know how to judge the
CHAPTER FIVE