26.
For a wonderfully clear introduction to this point, as well as a complete analysis of the law, see Robert P. Merges et al.,
27.
Thomas Jefferson, letter to Isaac Mcpherson, August 13, 1813, reprinted in
28.
For the classic discussion, see Kenneth J. Arrow, 'Economic Welfare and the Allocation of Resources for Invention,' in
29.
For a powerfully compelling problematization of the economic perspective in this context, see Boyle, 'Intellectual Property Policy Online,' 35–46. Boyle's work evinces the indeterminacy that economics ought to profess about whether increasing property rights over information will also increase the production of information.
30.
Some insist on calling this 'property'; see Frank H. Easterbrook, 'Intellectual Property Is Still Property,'
31.
This is the message of Justice Stephen Breyer's work on copyright, for example, 'The Uneasy Case for Copyright.'
32.
See
33.
For an extensive and balanced analysis, see William M. Landes and Richard A. Posner, 'An Economic Analysis of Copyright Law,'
34.
These limits come from both the limits in the copyright clause, which sets its purposes out quite clearly, and the First Amendment; see, for example,
35.
The 'first sale' doctrine was developed under 27 of the former Copyright Act (17 USC [1970]) and has since been adopted under 109(a) of the present Copyright Act; see
36.
Europeans like to say that 'moral rights' have been part of their system since the beginning of time, but as Professor Jane C. Ginsburg has shown with respect to France, they are actually a nineteenth-century creation; see 'A Tale of Two Copyrights: Literary Property in Revolutionary France and America,'
37.
Daniel Benoliel, 'Technological Standards, Inc.: Rethinking Cyberspace Regulative Epistemology,' 92
38.
See
39.
Stefik,