29
Daron Acemoglu, the MIT economist, and James Robinson, the Harvard political scientist, put the same point in more academic language. They predict that democracy will become more widespread with globalization, as it will make democracy more innocuous. In their view, globalization is likely to make ‘the elites and conservative parties to become more powerful and democracy to become less redistributive in the future, especially if new forms of representation for the majority – in both the political sphere and the workplace – do not emerge. Thus, democracy will become more consolidated: however, for those who expect democracy to transform society in the same way as British democracy did in the first half of the twentieth century, it may be a disappointing form of democracy’. J. Robinson & D. Acemoglu (2006),
30
A telling example in this regard is an opinion poll before the 2000 US presidential election which revealed that the most important reason cited by the respondents against either of the candidates was that he was ‘too political’. So many people rejecting someone who is seeking the biggest political office in the world on the ground that he is ‘too political’ is a testimony to the extent which the neo-liberals have succeeded in demonizing politics.
31
However, extension of franchise to poor people in European countries in the late 19th and the early 20th centuries did
32
See the literature reviews in A. Przeworski & F. Limongi (1993), ‘Political Regimes and Economic Growth’,
33
A. Sen, Democracy as a Universal Value,
34
One important dimension that we need to bear in mind when understanding the struggle for democracy in today’s developing countries is that universal suffrage now enjoys an unprecedented legitimacy. Since the end of the Second World War, selective franchising – once so ‘natural’ – has become simply unacceptable. Rulers now only have a binary choice – full democracy or no election. An army general who has come to power through a military
35
Technically speaking, the blacks in the southern states were disenfranchised
*
Their corruption was such that the very definition of corruption was different from what prevails today.When he was accused of corruption in Parliament in 1730, Robert Walpole freely admitted that he had great estates and asked: ‘having held some of the most lucrative offices for nearly 20 years, what could anyone expect, unless it was a crime to get estates by great office’. He turned the tables on his accusers by asking them, ‘how much greater a crime it must be to get an estate out of lesser offices.’ See Nield (2002),
*
The index should be taken with a grain of salt. As the name makes it clear, it is only measuring the ‘perception’ revealed in surveys of technical experts and businessmen, who have their own limited knowledge and biases. The problem with such a subjective measure is well illustrated by the fact that the perceptions of corruption in the Asian countries affected by the 1997 financial crisis suddenly rose significantly after the crisis, despite having almost constantly fallen in the preceding decade (see H-J. Chang [2000], ‘The Hazard of Moral Hazard – Untangling the Asian Crisis’,
*
The marked increase in corruption in post-Thatcher Britain, the pioneer of NPM, is a salutary lesson regarding market-based anti-corruption campaigns. Commenting on the experience, Robert Nield, a retired Cambridge economics professor and a member of the famous 1968 Fulton civil service reform committee, laments that ‘I cannot think of another instance where a modern democracy has systematically undone the system by which incorrupt public services were brought into being’. See Nield (2002),