De Regimine Principum, lib. II, cap. I-VII, where the economic foundations of a State are discussed.
  • Aquinas, Summa Theol., 2a 2æ, Q. LXXXIII, art. VI. For St. Antonino’s remarks to the same purpose, see Jarrett, St. Antonino and Mediæval Economics, p. 59.

  • Gratian, Decretum, pt. II, causa XII, Q. I, c. II, § 1.

  • A good account of St. Antonino’s theory of property is given by Ilgner, Die Volkswirthschaftlichen Anschauungen Antonins von Florenz, chap. X.

  • Sed si esset bonus legislator in patria indigente, deberet locare pro pretio magno huiusmodi mercatores⁠ ⁠… et non tantum eis et familiæ sustentationem necessariam invenire, sed etiam industriam, peritiam, et pericula omnia locare; ergo etiam hoc possunt ipsi in vendendo” (quoted Schreiber, Die volkswirthschaftlichen Anschauungen der Scholastik seit Thomas v. Aquin, p. 154).

  • Henry of Ghent, Aurea Quodlibeta, p. 42b (quoted Schreiber, Die volkswirthschaftlichen Anschauungen der Scholastik seit Thomas v. Aquin, p. 135).

  • Gratian, Decretum, pt. 1, dist. LXXXVIII, cap. XI.

  • Aquinas, Summa Theol., 2a 2æ, Q. LXXVII, art. IV.

  • Aquinas, Summa Theol., 2a 2æ, Q. LXXVII, art. IV. Trade is unobjectionable, “cum aliquis negotiationi intendit propter publicam utilitatem, ne scilicet res necessariæ ad vitam patriæ desint, et lucrum expetit, non quasi finem, sed quasi stipendium laboris.”

  • Henry of Langenstein, Tractatus bipartitus de contractibus emptionis et venditionis, I, 12 (quoted Schreiber, Die volkswirthschaftlichen Anschauungen der Scholastik seit Thomas v. Aquin, p. 197).

  • See here.

  • Examples of these stories are printed by Coulton, A Mediæval Garner, 1910, pp. 212⁠–⁠15, 298, and Social Life in England from the Conquest to the Reformation, 1919, p. 346.

  • The facts are given by Arturo Segre, Storia del Commercio, vol. I, p. 223. For a fuller account of credit and money-lending in Florence, see Doren, Studien aus der Florentiner Wirthschaftsgeschichte, vol. I, pp. 173⁠–⁠209.

  • Bruno Kuske, Quellen zur Geschichte des Kölner Handels und Verkehrs im Mittelalter, vol. III, 1923, pp. 197⁠–⁠8.

  • Early English Text Society, The Coventry Leet Book, ed. M. D. Harris, 1907⁠–⁠13, p. 544.

  • Wyclif, On the Seven Deadly Sins, chap. XXIV (Works of Wyclif, ed. T. Arnold, vol. III, pp. 154⁠–⁠5). The word rendered “loan” is “leeve” [? leene] in the text.

  • For examples of such cases see Early Chancery Proceedings, Bdle. LXIV, nos. 291 and 1089; Bdle. XXXVII, no. 38; Bdle. XLVI, no. 307. They are discussed in some detail in my introduction to Thomas Wilson’s Discourse Upon Usury, 1925, pp. 28⁠–⁠9.

  • Hist. MSS. Com., MSS. of Marquis of Lothian, p. 27; Selden Soc., Leet Jurisdiction in the City of Norwich, p. 35.

  • Aquinas, Summa Theol., 1a 2æ, Q. XCV, art. II.

  • On the Seven Deadly Sins, chap. XXIV (Works of Wyclif, ed. T. Arnold, vol. III, p. 153): “Bot men of lawe and marchauntis and chapmen and vitelers synnen more in avarice then done pore laboreres. And this token hereof; for now ben thei pore, and now ben thei ful riche, for wronges that thei done.”

  • E.g., Ægidius Lessinus, De Usuris, cap. IX, pt. I: “Tantum res estimatur juste, quantum ad utilitatem possidentis refertur, et tantum juste valet, quantum sine fraude vendi potest.⁠ ⁠… Omnis translatio facta libera voluntate dominorum juste fit;” Johannes Buridanus, Quæstiones super decem libros Ethicorum Aristotelis, V, 23: “Si igitur rem suam sic alienat, ipse secundum suam estimationem non damnificatur, sed lucratur; igitur non injustum patitur.” Both writers are discussed by Schreiber (Die volkswirthschaftlichen Anschauungen der Scholastik seit Thomas v. Aquin, pp. 161⁠–⁠71 and 177⁠–⁠91). The theory of Buridanus appears extraordinarily modern; but he is careful to emphasize that prices should be fixed “secundum utilitatem et necessitatem totius communitatis,” not “penes necessitatem ementis vel vendentis.”

  • St. Antonino, Summa Theologica, pars II, tit. I, cap. VIII, § 1, and cap. XVI, § III. An account of St. Antonino’s theory of prices is given by Ilgner, Die volkswirthschaftlichen Anschauungen Antonins von Florenz, chap. IV; Jarrett, St. Antonino and Mediæval Economics; and Schreiber, Die volkswirthschaftlichen Anschauungen der Scholastik seit Thomas v. Aquin, pp. 217⁠–⁠23. Its interest consists in the attempts to maintain the principle of the just price, while making allowance for practical necessities.

  • Henry of Langenstein, Tractatus bipartitus de contractibus emptionis et venditionis, I, 11, 12 (quoted Schreiber, Die volkswirthschaftlichen Anschauungen der Scholastik seit Thomas v. Aquin, pp. 198⁠–⁠200).

  • For these examples see Cal. of Early Mayor’s Court Rolls of the City of London, ed. A. H. Thomas, pp. 259⁠–⁠60; Records of the City of Norwich, ed. W. Hudson and J. C. Tingey, vol. I, 1906, p. 227; Cal. of Early Mayor’s Court Rolls, p. 132; J. M. Wilson, The Worcester Liber Albus, 1920, pp. 199⁠–⁠200, 212⁠–⁠13. The question of the legitimacy of rent-charges and of the profits of partnership

  • Добавить отзыв
    ВСЕ ОТЗЫВЫ О КНИГЕ В ИЗБРАННОЕ

    0

    Вы можете отметить интересные вам фрагменты текста, которые будут доступны по уникальной ссылке в адресной строке браузера.

    Отметить Добавить цитату